United States: Why Robot Taxes Won't Work

Last Updated: October 10 2018
Article by William H. Weissman

Those who find their livelihoods threatened by disruptive technologies have long rallied against those new innovations, finding an ally in governments willing to slow adoption. Queen Elizabeth I's declaration that all subjects wear knit caps, for example, created an industry and provided work to those who might otherwise not have had any. William Lee developed the stocking frame in 1589 to alleviate the time-consuming labor required to produce knit caps.

Lee sought a patent from Queen Elizabeth, who rejected it, observing that the invention threatened knitters and "would assuredly bring them ruin by depriving them of employment, thus making them beggars."1  Recognizing the implications that the technology could have on existing jobs, the queen believed that Lee's invention was simply too dangerous to implement.

Given her concern for the current lot of her subjects, Elizabeth's lack of foresight to see the increases in work the spinning loom would generate should not be held against her. But notwithstanding her attempt to forestall progress, the stocking frame was implemented, driving down the price of knit caps and cloth. That led English Luddites to smash the stocking frames that were killing their jobs, but to no avail, because innovation won and protectionism lost. The stocking frame is one of many examples.

One of the anticipated consequences of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (P.L.115-97) enacted in December 2017 is the accelerated adoption of automation technologies that have the potential to displace workers over the next several years. While a potential boon for some, not everyone likes the notion that technology is rapidly replacing certain jobs. For example, in February 2017 Bill Gates proposed a robot tax to offset the costs of retraining workers displaced by technology.2

Gates is hardly the first to sound the alarm about "technological unemployment." In 1930 John Maynard Keynes, in his famous essay "Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren," posited two reasons why unemployment was not a significant issue before the rise of industrialization: "the remarkable absence of important technical improvements and the failure of capital to accumulate." Keynes then surmised that the rapid rise of capital and technical innovations in the early 1900s

is hurting us and bringing difficult problems to solve. . . . We are being afflicted with a new disease of which some readers may not yet have heard the name, but of which they will hear a great deal in the years to come — namely, technological unemployment. This means unemployment due to our discovery of means of economizing the use of labour outrunning the pace at which we can find new uses for labour.3

Keynes believed technological unemployment to be a "temporary phase of maladjustment." Besides overlooking numerous labor laws over the centuries as a reason for the absence of structural unemployment, time has also proven Keynes incorrect, insofar as technology continues to cause structural unemployment by shifting the nature of work.

Between Keynes and Gates came the National Commission on Technology, Automation, and Economic Progress. In its 1966 report, "Technology and the American Economy," the commission observed that "the basic fact is that technology eliminates jobs, not work."4 Contrary to those predicting that robots will end all jobs, the current data show that when people and technology mix, work increases. What changes is how work is distributed among jobs. Boston University Law School professor James Bessen explained that problem in a March 2016 article for Harvard Business Review:

The reality is that most jobs using computers have seen growing employment, not job losses. For example, jobs for bank tellers have been growing since the deployment of ATMs. And this pattern is typical overall.

However, much of the growth in jobs using computers comes at the expense of other occupations. Consider, for example, the effect of computers on typographers. Desktop publishing dramatically reduced jobs for typographers in the 1980s, yet it was not a case of computers replacing typographers — it was the substitution of one occupation for another. . . .

The point is that computers contribute to declining employment in some occupations but the net effect of computers is not a decline in the total number of jobs. Computer automation creates about as many jobs as are lost through substitution. Thus computers are not causing technological unemployment.5

Perhaps like EF Hutton, when Bill Gates talks, people listen. Some were critical. Former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers, in an op-ed in the Financial Times, said that while Gates was right about "the gravity of the problem," a robot tax was "misguided" and little more than "protectionism against progress."6

But others listening seemed to embrace Gates's idea, such as San Francisco Supervisor Jane Kim, who in August 2017 proposed a "Jobs for the Future Fund." Wired reported that Kim, who got the fund idea from Gates, believes that "proceeds from the tax would bankroll things like job retraining, free community college, or perhaps a universal basic income — countermeasures Kim thinks might make a robotic future more bearable for humans."7

Gates, Kim, and others have played on populist fears that anthropomorphic robots will replace all humans, à la The Terminator. Thus, because robots will look like us and take our jobs, we should tax them as individuals.8 But using fear to design tax policy is a mistake.

For one, there is no clear agreement on what constitutes a robot, meaning it is unclear what to tax and what not to tax. Without well-thought-out definitions, there is no way to administer a robot tax. Take for example a case in which a court addressed whether life-sized, singing mechanical puppets at a multi-location restaurant venue catering to children's events were "performing" such that Maryland's admissions and amusement tax applied.9 The court applied the standard approach of taking the plain and ordinary meaning of the term "performing," which requires a "formal exhibition of skill or talent," and held that "because a preprogrammed robot has no 'skill' and therefore leaves no room for spontaneous human flaw in an exhibition, it cannot 'perform' a piece of music any more than can a jukebox."10 As such, the admissions and amusement tax did not apply.

While the court's analysis may be textbook appellate review, it seems inadequate to determine the highly complex nature of automation technologies or artificial intelligence today. Is a calculator that can help an employee perform tasks quicker than adding up numbers with pen and paper a robot for tax purposes? Or is the calculator a robot only if it uses formulas or algorithms programmed by individuals? And how do we tell if the calculator results in a loss of jobs, or simply slows the hiring of more workers in the future? Does that difference even matter, and if so, why? These are just a few of the many unanswered questions that must be addressed by any robot tax discussion. Otherwise, a robot tax is little more than populist rhetoric without substance.

Another problem is that from a tax administration perspective, robots pay no income tax because they do not earn income, pay no sales tax because they do not purchase items, and pay no property tax because they do not own anything. As such, any robot tax — even if imposed on businesses that implement robots — would be borne exclusively by humans in the form of higher prices for products or services and lower profits, dividends, or wages. Like any other expense, taxes must be paid from revenue generated by the company, and more expense devoted to taxes means less revenue for other aspects of the business. Business taxes affect customers and employees, not just owners. To ensure that robot taxes are not largely borne by the very same individuals they are intended to help, thought must be given to the structure of any technology tax.

That leads to yet another problem with a local proposal like Kim's: Far too few people — only San Francisco businesses — would bear the tax to make an appreciable difference in a larger societal problem. That is always a concern in using state or local tax initiatives to solve regional, national, or international problems. California's cap-and trade program is a good example of a state tax attempting to solve an international problem. While driving up Californians' costs for virtually everything, cap and trade has seemingly done little to curb greenhouse gas emissions worldwide, even as there has been some small reduction in California greenhouse gases.11

Even if Kim's proposal were adopted statewide, it would not be effective at slowing the shift in work from one kind of job to another, or even jobs from one jurisdiction to another. Rather, such a tax in San Francisco or even California would just be an invitation for the other 49 states to court California businesses looking to expand and innovate. As one commentator put it, "robots don't complain about relocating."12

Imposing taxes is as ineffective a form of protectionism as refusing to grant a patent. For example, Indonesia has long imposed a higher excise tax on machine-made cigarettes compared with hand-rolled cigarettes in an attempt to slow down automation of an industry that once employed large numbers of low-skilled workers, yet the industry continues to grow. In August 2017 South Korea unveiled a tax plan that is not really a technology tax, but a reduction in the tax incentives that were speeding the adoption of automation technologies. It seems very doubtful that South Korea's attempt to slow innovation will work.

To be fair, neither Gates nor Kim has laid out any detailed robot tax plan, but they have expressed concerns about how technology is affecting people's lives and raised awareness of the need to help those individuals. The real problem, however, is not work, which is growing, but jobs, which are shifting. That is an education issue, not a technology issue. No longer can an individual who performed one kind of largely unskilled manual labor readily find another job performing that type of labor. Manufacturing jobs now require more technical skills, which in turn require education or job training. While Gates and Kim both reference the need for job training, the focus on a tax to pay for it is putting the cart before the horse. Taxes would not keep existing jobs from disappearing or new jobs from being created any more than liquor taxes keep people from drinking. Taxes are an inefficient and, more importantly, ineffective way to prevent behavior.

If people like Gates and Kim are serious about addressing the impact of technology on the shifting nature of work (and not merely jobs), they should start with education reform,13 which is generally the largest slice of most state and local funding. Looking at how to redesign public and private education from preschoolers to adults — using the billions already being spent — is far more important than imposing new technology taxes that are at best an indirect attempt to solve the wrong problem.

***

Reprinted from State Tax Notes, April 9, 2018, p. 125

Footnotes

1 Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, Why Nations Fail, 181-182 (2012).

2 Kevin Delaney, "The Robot That Takes Your Job Should Pay Taxes, Says Bill Gates," Quartz  (Feb. 17, 2017).

3 Italics in the original.

4 National Commission on Technology, Automation, and Economic Progress, "Technology and the American Economy," Vol. 1, at 9 (Feb. 1966).

5 James Bessen, "Computers Don't Kill Jobs but Do Increase Inequality," Harvard Business Review, Mar. 24, 2016 (emphasis in original).

6 Lawrence Summers, "Robots Are Wealth Creators and Taxing Them Is Illogical," Financial Times, Mar. 5, 2017.

7 Matt Simon, "Tax the Rich and the Robots? California's Thinking About It," Wired.com  (Aug. 24, 2017).

8 This view seems to assume that technology is somehow bad, but most humans invent technologies that they believe will improve society. Edison's invention of the light bulb may have greatly diminished candlemakers' work, but his intention was to provide bright light to the world, not put an industry out of business. In promoting taxes intended to discourage behavior — think sin taxes on tobacco products — it helps if the object of the tax is something seen as bad. But how can inventions that improve our lives be demonized? The psychology of taxes makes it hard to impose robot taxes without positioning it as if robots are like humans stealing our jobs. But technology itself is neither good nor bad. How humans use technology is what defines the outcomes.

9 Comptroller of Treasury v. Family Entertainment Centers Inc., 519 A.2d 1337 (Md. 1987).

10 Id. at 1339.

11 In 2015, the last year data is apparently available, greenhouse gases dropped about 1.5 percent in California. However, the evidence seems to suggest that cap and trade itself is responsible for very little of that reduction, with a down economy caused by the Great Recession, an increase in electric cars, and other improvements in clean energy technology being largely responsible for the drop. See  Dale Kasler, "California's Cap-and-Trade Program Is Costly, Controversial. But How Does It Work?" The Sacramento Bee, July 19, 2017.

While it may also be great to be a leader in innovation, and other governments may follow suit, it is no great bargain for California residents to absorb the costs so that perhaps Quebec and Midwestern states will join the cause. Even if reducing greenhouse gases is good for society, it is questionable whether Californians should be shouldering that high cost alone. If liberals really want to address growing inequality in California, reevaluating expensive and questionable programs like cap and trade would be a good place to start.

12 Robert Kovacev, "The Challenges of Administering a Robot Tax," Law360, Sept. 25, 2017.

13 Again, in fairness to Gates, the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation is doing extensive work on education reform, both in K-12 education and higher education. Visit www.gatesfoundation.org for information on the many education initiatives the Gates Foundation supports.

The content of this article is intended to provide a general guide to the subject matter. Specialist advice should be sought about your specific circumstances.

To print this article, all you need is to be registered on Mondaq.com.

Click to Login as an existing user or Register so you can print this article.

Authors
William H. Weissman
 
In association with
Related Topics
 
Related Articles
 
Related Video
Up-coming Events Search
Tools
Print
Font Size:
Translation
Channels
Mondaq on Twitter
 
Register for Access and our Free Biweekly Alert for
This service is completely free. Access 250,000 archived articles from 100+ countries and get a personalised email twice a week covering developments (and yes, our lawyers like to think you’ve read our Disclaimer).
 
Email Address
Company Name
Password
Confirm Password
Position
Mondaq Topics -- Select your Interests
 Accounting
 Anti-trust
 Commercial
 Compliance
 Consumer
 Criminal
 Employment
 Energy
 Environment
 Family
 Finance
 Government
 Healthcare
 Immigration
 Insolvency
 Insurance
 International
 IP
 Law Performance
 Law Practice
 Litigation
 Media & IT
 Privacy
 Real Estate
 Strategy
 Tax
 Technology
 Transport
 Wealth Mgt
Regions
Africa
Asia
Asia Pacific
Australasia
Canada
Caribbean
Europe
European Union
Latin America
Middle East
U.K.
United States
Worldwide Updates
Registration (you must scroll down to set your data preferences)

Mondaq Ltd requires you to register and provide information that personally identifies you, including your content preferences, for three primary purposes (full details of Mondaq’s use of your personal data can be found in our Privacy and Cookies Notice):

  • To allow you to personalize the Mondaq websites you are visiting to show content ("Content") relevant to your interests.
  • To enable features such as password reminder, news alerts, email a colleague, and linking from Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) to your website.
  • To produce demographic feedback for our content providers ("Contributors") who contribute Content for free for your use.

Mondaq hopes that our registered users will support us in maintaining our free to view business model by consenting to our use of your personal data as described below.

Mondaq has a "free to view" business model. Our services are paid for by Contributors in exchange for Mondaq providing them with access to information about who accesses their content. Once personal data is transferred to our Contributors they become a data controller of this personal data. They use it to measure the response that their articles are receiving, as a form of market research. They may also use it to provide Mondaq users with information about their products and services.

Details of each Contributor to which your personal data will be transferred is clearly stated within the Content that you access. For full details of how this Contributor will use your personal data, you should review the Contributor’s own Privacy Notice.

Please indicate your preference below:

Yes, I am happy to support Mondaq in maintaining its free to view business model by agreeing to allow Mondaq to share my personal data with Contributors whose Content I access
No, I do not want Mondaq to share my personal data with Contributors

Also please let us know whether you are happy to receive communications promoting products and services offered by Mondaq:

Yes, I am happy to received promotional communications from Mondaq
No, please do not send me promotional communications from Mondaq
Terms & Conditions

Mondaq.com (the Website) is owned and managed by Mondaq Ltd (Mondaq). Mondaq grants you a non-exclusive, revocable licence to access the Website and associated services, such as the Mondaq News Alerts (Services), subject to and in consideration of your compliance with the following terms and conditions of use (Terms). Your use of the Website and/or Services constitutes your agreement to the Terms. Mondaq may terminate your use of the Website and Services if you are in breach of these Terms or if Mondaq decides to terminate the licence granted hereunder for any reason whatsoever.

Use of www.mondaq.com

To Use Mondaq.com you must be: eighteen (18) years old or over; legally capable of entering into binding contracts; and not in any way prohibited by the applicable law to enter into these Terms in the jurisdiction which you are currently located.

You may use the Website as an unregistered user, however, you are required to register as a user if you wish to read the full text of the Content or to receive the Services.

You may not modify, publish, transmit, transfer or sell, reproduce, create derivative works from, distribute, perform, link, display, or in any way exploit any of the Content, in whole or in part, except as expressly permitted in these Terms or with the prior written consent of Mondaq. You may not use electronic or other means to extract details or information from the Content. Nor shall you extract information about users or Contributors in order to offer them any services or products.

In your use of the Website and/or Services you shall: comply with all applicable laws, regulations, directives and legislations which apply to your Use of the Website and/or Services in whatever country you are physically located including without limitation any and all consumer law, export control laws and regulations; provide to us true, correct and accurate information and promptly inform us in the event that any information that you have provided to us changes or becomes inaccurate; notify Mondaq immediately of any circumstances where you have reason to believe that any Intellectual Property Rights or any other rights of any third party may have been infringed; co-operate with reasonable security or other checks or requests for information made by Mondaq from time to time; and at all times be fully liable for the breach of any of these Terms by a third party using your login details to access the Website and/or Services

however, you shall not: do anything likely to impair, interfere with or damage or cause harm or distress to any persons, or the network; do anything that will infringe any Intellectual Property Rights or other rights of Mondaq or any third party; or use the Website, Services and/or Content otherwise than in accordance with these Terms; use any trade marks or service marks of Mondaq or the Contributors, or do anything which may be seen to take unfair advantage of the reputation and goodwill of Mondaq or the Contributors, or the Website, Services and/or Content.

Mondaq reserves the right, in its sole discretion, to take any action that it deems necessary and appropriate in the event it considers that there is a breach or threatened breach of the Terms.

Mondaq’s Rights and Obligations

Unless otherwise expressly set out to the contrary, nothing in these Terms shall serve to transfer from Mondaq to you, any Intellectual Property Rights owned by and/or licensed to Mondaq and all rights, title and interest in and to such Intellectual Property Rights will remain exclusively with Mondaq and/or its licensors.

Mondaq shall use its reasonable endeavours to make the Website and Services available to you at all times, but we cannot guarantee an uninterrupted and fault free service.

Mondaq reserves the right to make changes to the services and/or the Website or part thereof, from time to time, and we may add, remove, modify and/or vary any elements of features and functionalities of the Website or the services.

Mondaq also reserves the right from time to time to monitor your Use of the Website and/or services.

Disclaimer

The Content is general information only. It is not intended to constitute legal advice or seek to be the complete and comprehensive statement of the law, nor is it intended to address your specific requirements or provide advice on which reliance should be placed. Mondaq and/or its Contributors and other suppliers make no representations about the suitability of the information contained in the Content for any purpose. All Content provided "as is" without warranty of any kind. Mondaq and/or its Contributors and other suppliers hereby exclude and disclaim all representations, warranties or guarantees with regard to the Content, including all implied warranties and conditions of merchantability, fitness for a particular purpose, title and non-infringement. To the maximum extent permitted by law, Mondaq expressly excludes all representations, warranties, obligations, and liabilities arising out of or in connection with all Content. In no event shall Mondaq and/or its respective suppliers be liable for any special, indirect or consequential damages or any damages whatsoever resulting from loss of use, data or profits, whether in an action of contract, negligence or other tortious action, arising out of or in connection with the use of the Content or performance of Mondaq’s Services.

General

Mondaq may alter or amend these Terms by amending them on the Website. By continuing to Use the Services and/or the Website after such amendment, you will be deemed to have accepted any amendment to these Terms.

These Terms shall be governed by and construed in accordance with the laws of England and Wales and you irrevocably submit to the exclusive jurisdiction of the courts of England and Wales to settle any dispute which may arise out of or in connection with these Terms. If you live outside the United Kingdom, English law shall apply only to the extent that English law shall not deprive you of any legal protection accorded in accordance with the law of the place where you are habitually resident ("Local Law"). In the event English law deprives you of any legal protection which is accorded to you under Local Law, then these terms shall be governed by Local Law and any dispute or claim arising out of or in connection with these Terms shall be subject to the non-exclusive jurisdiction of the courts where you are habitually resident.

You may print and keep a copy of these Terms, which form the entire agreement between you and Mondaq and supersede any other communications or advertising in respect of the Service and/or the Website.

No delay in exercising or non-exercise by you and/or Mondaq of any of its rights under or in connection with these Terms shall operate as a waiver or release of each of your or Mondaq’s right. Rather, any such waiver or release must be specifically granted in writing signed by the party granting it.

If any part of these Terms is held unenforceable, that part shall be enforced to the maximum extent permissible so as to give effect to the intent of the parties, and the Terms shall continue in full force and effect.

Mondaq shall not incur any liability to you on account of any loss or damage resulting from any delay or failure to perform all or any part of these Terms if such delay or failure is caused, in whole or in part, by events, occurrences, or causes beyond the control of Mondaq. Such events, occurrences or causes will include, without limitation, acts of God, strikes, lockouts, server and network failure, riots, acts of war, earthquakes, fire and explosions.

By clicking Register you state you have read and agree to our Terms and Conditions