India: Dancing In The Dark: Electricity Reform After California

Last Updated: 30 November 2001
Article by David Renton

David Renton, a partner in Herbert Smith’s Hong Kong practice, looks at the impact of the California experience on Asian Governments plans to restructure their electricity industries – in many cases an unavoidable necessity. This article first appeared in Project Finance International – Asia Pacific Review Supplement July 2001 and is used with their kind permission.

There is no alternative…

Passing the Philippines’ Electric Power Industry Reform Act of 2001 – a law that was more than six years in the making – should be seen not so much as a vote of confidence in competitive electricity markets as an admission that the way that the electricity industry is currently organised in the Philippines and throughout much of Asia is unsustainable. President Macagapal-Arroyo’s announcement, even as the electricity reform bill was being passed, that amending legislation may be required to protect electricity consumers against "arbitrary" price increases betrays a nagging worry over whether it really is a good idea to leave electricity pricing to market forces. What forced the hand of the bill’s opponents, who were mainly concerned about the size of the liabilities that the Philippines Government would have to assume as part of any restructuring and privatisation of the National Power Corporation (NPC), was the realisation that, until NPC’s monopoly over the supply of bulk power is broken, there would be no way of raising sufficient finance to satisfy the growing demand for electricity in the Philippines.

The same picture is emerging throughout Asia. Governments initially viewed electricity competition as a way of getting cheap electricity without the need for government subsidy. California served as a timely reminder that competition can cause electricity prices to go up as well as down, something that had evidently escaped the California Legislature when it pegged retail electricity tariffs at 10% below pre-competition levels whilst deregulating wholesale prices. Worse was the huge transfer of wealth from electricity consumers to generating companies that occurred in California as a result of the imbalance between supply and demand. If repeated in Asia, such an imbalance in a competitive market could threaten political stability and provide independent power producers, many of whom would be foreign, with a huge windfall at the country’s expense. Despite such nightmarish thoughts, Asian governments continue to pursue plans to restructure their electricity industry though more slowly than before.

…but getting the policy right can take time

Competition remains an important element in the restructuring of the electricity industry in Asia and, in the case of India, is being given a much greater role now than before the California crisis. In 1992, the government of Prime Minister Narashima Rao announced a package of measures designed to attract foreign investors willing to finance new power stations using the BOO/BOT model, including a tariff that offered guaranteed minimum returns on equity, protection against local currency depreciation, generous tax breaks and government guarantees. These measures succeeded in getting the attention of foreign investors but very few projects were actually implemented because the Government of India quickly got cold feet about its own policy. It worried that it had been far too generous in the returns it was offering and, above all, it worried about the irresponsibility of the State Electricity Boards (SEBs), the monopoly purchasers of power in their States, which were blithely signing long term commitments for thousands of megawatts of generating capacity at higher prices than they could re-sell it for. Although the Government of India had agreed to give counter-guarantees for only eight projects, it was concerned that the deficits that the SEBs would incur as a result of these contracts would spell economic disaster for the country.

The Government of India then turned its attention to reforming the SEBs, a delicate matter because the SEBs are under the jurisdiction of the State Governments rather than the Union Government in New Delhi. Several States, beginning with the State of Orissa, were persuaded to embark on a programme to reform their SEBs with funding provided by the World Bank, the Asian Development Bank and bilateral agencies such as the UK’s Department for International Development. The reforms consisted of separating the SEBs’ power generation, transmission and distribution businesses into separate companies to promote greater transparency, privatising the generation and, in some cases, the distribution businesses and creating new independent regulatory agencies to supervise the new electricity companies and increase their autonomy from government by acting as a buffer between the electricity companies and the politicians.

Although these reforms are widely regarded as a step in the right direction, there has been disappointment that they did not achieve the improvements in the State electricity sector that were hoped for. The main problem was that there was no competition to spur the new electricity companies to improve their performance. The new transmission companies continued to be wholly owned by the State Governments and, as a result, inherited many of the problems that had plagued the unrestructured SEBs. These Gridcos and Transcos continue to enjoy a monopoly over the purchase of power for resale within their States and their financial and operating weakness affects the performance of the rest of the industry.

Electricity reformers in India are now to put pressure on the SEBs and their successors to reform. The Indian Power Minister has announced that the Government intends to seek Parliament’s approval of a new law that will allow generating companies to sell power at market prices directly to large consumers and other bulk purchasers instead of selling it exclusively to a State owned transmission company. At first blush this seems like a revolutionary step since it would tend to undermine the tariff of cross-subsidies that large consumers pay for the benefit of agricultural and residential consumers. On closer inspection, however, it is clear that the advocates of the proposed new market structure intend to keep the existing cross-subsidies largely intact to ensure that electricity remains affordable for the poorest sections of Indian society; the cross-subsidies will simply be made transparent and imposed as a separate levy rather than being bundled into electricity prices as they are at present.

When will they ever learn?

India, like California before it, may be falling into the trap of thinking of competition as a cure for all ills instead of simply a way of allocating resources that may have negative as well as positive consequences.

  • Is it really possible to create a market that leaves the pricing of electricity to market forces whilst at the same time ensuring that prices remain affordable for vulnerable groups, particularly in India where the consumers that regard themselves as vulnerable are a very large percentage of the voting population?
  • Has India really considered the legal and political disputes that are likely to arise in a federal system over the level of subsidy to be offered in a particular State and whether the way that the subsidies are provided is a barrier to the development of an efficient national wholesale power market?
  • Is deregulation desirable at the present time in view of the shortfall of generating capacity in many parts of the country and the inadequacy of the interconnections between the different regional grids ?
  • How quickly could the market respond tohigh prices in view of the obstacles to commissioning new generation and transmission projects, including red tape, corruption, lack of finance and investor doubts about the enforceability of contracts as a result of the disputes over Enron’s Dabhol project?

The mistakes that were made in California could easily be repeated in Asia. The power pool that is to be established in Thailand, for example, seems to have been heavily influenced by the California model, judging from a report dated November 2000 and posted on the National Energy Policy Office’s website in March 2001. One area of concern is the extent to which Thailand proposes to rely on a spot market to set electricity prices. Although the spot market will not be mandatory – generators will be able to contract directly with eligible customers, retailers and other intermediaries outside the pool – a company responsible for supplying ineligible customers or eligible customers who do not wish to contract directly outside the Pool will be required to buy all of its electricity in the spot market. It will be prohibited from contracting forward, though individual consumers will be able to hedge their exposure to the spot price by contracting with unregulated "retailcos" if they wish, though few consumers are likely to buy enough electricity or have the necessary interval metering to make hedging worthwhile.

The US Federal Energy Commission blamed similar restrictions on contracting forward for the unreasonably high prices in the California market because they prevented the companies subject to the restriction from influencing market behaviour – they simply became passive price takers. This should not matter if no one in the market has market power but this will rarely be the case. Significant barriers to building new generating and transmission capacity may allow generating companies, either individually or through tacit collusion, to keep generation prices above the levels that would prevail in a more open market. Insufficient competition in the Pool can also dry up the forward market for those customers who can contract outside the Pool – generating companies may prefer to remain exposed to a spot price they can influence than contract forward at prices that may turn out to be significantly below the market price. This is why the UK Government chose to abandon its relatively successful electricity pool in which most power purchasers participated as passive price takers and replace it with a market that relies on forward contracting. For now, electricity prices in England and Wales have fallen significantly as a result.

If you have to ask, you can’t afford it.

The greatest concern of most Asian governments in the aftermath of the California crisis is the risk of price volatility. Most Asian governments now agree that the root cause of the California crisis was not the flaws in the market model but the fact that the demand for electricity was growing much faster than the growth in generation and transmission capacity. Given the roller coaster ride that Asian economies have experienced in recent years, similar imbalances between supply and demand are likely to occur repeatedly in Asia and, in some countries, are a fact of life. The willingness of electricity consumers to pay high electricity prices when capacity is tight will be much less in developing countries than it is in the West, particularly when the high prices are being paid to foreign investor companies.

Competition with Asian characteristics

Because of the concern about the effects of liberalising electricity prices, it seems unlikely that a truly competitive market model will emerge in Asia. What is more likely is that governments will introduce highly managed pools that will be used for trading marginal quantities of power at market prices. Pools will be designed primarily to facilitate third party access to transmission networks. They will allow newly privatised companies to trade surplus power with each other and improve the utilisation of their assets. They will also allow independent power producers to sell power to several different off-takers, thereby diluting their credit risk and mitigating the impact of an off-taker’s default. Allowing generating companies and off-takers even limited choice will help reduce the market power of the State-owned monopolies and help put pressure on them to reform in order to stave off demands from discontented captive customers for the right to buy their power in the market. Governments are unlikely to rely on pools to match supply and demand on a long term basis; governments will continue for the time being to plan their electricity systems and decide which transmission and generation projects to approve.

Pricing in these managed pools may be based on bids from competing generators, though governments will almost certainly retain the power to intervene and punish generating companies for abusive bidding in order to keep market prices within an acceptable range. Alternatively, generation bids may be regulated by reference to underlying costs. In India, the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission has proposed a wholesale spot market in which prices are calculated every fifteen minutes by reference to system frequency. When frequency is high, indicating too much generation, the market price drops to zero to encourage generators to back down their plants. When frequency is low, indicating insufficient generation, the pool price will increase, depending on frequency, to a level sufficient to incentivise standby generation to begin producing power. These prices are paid only in relation to "imbalance energy", that is the difference between the quantity of energy that a market participant contracted in advance to supply or take in a particular 15 minute period and the quantity actually supplied or taken. The CERC intends to review pool prices from time to time to ensure that they continue to provide the right incentives and will adjust them as necessary to reflect changes in fuel prices.

The concept of a managed pool may well be anathema to economists but pools must also serve political objectives. There is little sign that liberalisation has taken politics out of the electricity industry – quite the reverse. In California, the market designers and politicians failed to connect, with disastrous results. The same mistakes must be avoided in Asia. Managed pools will not look much like the competitive electricity markets in Europe, Australia or North America. Generation prices may well be regulated instead of being left to market forces. They will not necessarily use marginal or nodal pricing since the decision where and when to build new generating and transmission capacity will still be influenced more by governments than by price signals in the market. Although governments will want prices in the pool to be reasonably cost reflective to promote economically efficient trading, they will also want market prices to be fair and reasonable in the eyes of the public.

The passage of the Philippines’ Electric Power Industry Reform Act of 2001, despite the California crisis, indicates how far governments in Asia have come in thinking about how the electricity industry should be structured and the role of the private sector but the California crisis has made them cautious about embracing Western market models. We now face the challenge of developing a trading model for electricity that will work in Asia. If we don’t, we may all be dancing in the dark.

"© Herbert Smith 2002

The content of this article does not constitute legal advice and should not be relied on as such. Specific advice should be sought about your specific circumstances.

For more information on this or other Herbert Smith publications, please email us."

To print this article, all you need is to be registered on

Click to Login as an existing user or Register so you can print this article.

In association with
Up-coming Events Search
Font Size:
Mondaq on Twitter
Register for Access and our Free Biweekly Alert for
This service is completely free. Access 250,000 archived articles from 100+ countries and get a personalised email twice a week covering developments (and yes, our lawyers like to think you’ve read our Disclaimer).
Email Address
Company Name
Confirm Password
Mondaq Topics -- Select your Interests
 Law Performance
 Law Practice
 Media & IT
 Real Estate
 Wealth Mgt
Asia Pacific
European Union
Latin America
Middle East
United States
Worldwide Updates
Check to state you have read and
agree to our Terms and Conditions

Terms & Conditions and Privacy Statement (the Website) is owned and managed by Mondaq Ltd and as a user you are granted a non-exclusive, revocable license to access the Website under its terms and conditions of use. Your use of the Website constitutes your agreement to the following terms and conditions of use. Mondaq Ltd may terminate your use of the Website if you are in breach of these terms and conditions or if Mondaq Ltd decides to terminate your license of use for whatever reason.

Use of

You may use the Website but are required to register as a user if you wish to read the full text of the content and articles available (the Content). You may not modify, publish, transmit, transfer or sell, reproduce, create derivative works from, distribute, perform, link, display, or in any way exploit any of the Content, in whole or in part, except as expressly permitted in these terms & conditions or with the prior written consent of Mondaq Ltd. You may not use electronic or other means to extract details or information about’s content, users or contributors in order to offer them any services or products which compete directly or indirectly with Mondaq Ltd’s services and products.


Mondaq Ltd and/or its respective suppliers make no representations about the suitability of the information contained in the documents and related graphics published on this server for any purpose. All such documents and related graphics are provided "as is" without warranty of any kind. Mondaq Ltd and/or its respective suppliers hereby disclaim all warranties and conditions with regard to this information, including all implied warranties and conditions of merchantability, fitness for a particular purpose, title and non-infringement. In no event shall Mondaq Ltd and/or its respective suppliers be liable for any special, indirect or consequential damages or any damages whatsoever resulting from loss of use, data or profits, whether in an action of contract, negligence or other tortious action, arising out of or in connection with the use or performance of information available from this server.

The documents and related graphics published on this server could include technical inaccuracies or typographical errors. Changes are periodically added to the information herein. Mondaq Ltd and/or its respective suppliers may make improvements and/or changes in the product(s) and/or the program(s) described herein at any time.


Mondaq Ltd requires you to register and provide information that personally identifies you, including what sort of information you are interested in, for three primary purposes:

  • To allow you to personalize the Mondaq websites you are visiting.
  • To enable features such as password reminder, newsletter alerts, email a colleague, and linking from Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) to your website.
  • To produce demographic feedback for our information providers who provide information free for your use.

Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) do not sell or provide your details to third parties other than information providers. The reason we provide our information providers with this information is so that they can measure the response their articles are receiving and provide you with information about their products and services.

If you do not want us to provide your name and email address you may opt out by clicking here .

If you do not wish to receive any future announcements of products and services offered by Mondaq by clicking here .

Information Collection and Use

We require site users to register with Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) to view the free information on the site. We also collect information from our users at several different points on the websites: this is so that we can customise the sites according to individual usage, provide 'session-aware' functionality, and ensure that content is acquired and developed appropriately. This gives us an overall picture of our user profiles, which in turn shows to our Editorial Contributors the type of person they are reaching by posting articles on Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) – meaning more free content for registered users.

We are only able to provide the material on the Mondaq (and its affiliate sites) site free to site visitors because we can pass on information about the pages that users are viewing and the personal information users provide to us (e.g. email addresses) to reputable contributing firms such as law firms who author those pages. We do not sell or rent information to anyone else other than the authors of those pages, who may change from time to time. Should you wish us not to disclose your details to any of these parties, please tick the box above or tick the box marked "Opt out of Registration Information Disclosure" on the Your Profile page. We and our author organisations may only contact you via email or other means if you allow us to do so. Users can opt out of contact when they register on the site, or send an email to with “no disclosure” in the subject heading

Mondaq News Alerts

In order to receive Mondaq News Alerts, users have to complete a separate registration form. This is a personalised service where users choose regions and topics of interest and we send it only to those users who have requested it. Users can stop receiving these Alerts by going to the Mondaq News Alerts page and deselecting all interest areas. In the same way users can amend their personal preferences to add or remove subject areas.


A cookie is a small text file written to a user’s hard drive that contains an identifying user number. The cookies do not contain any personal information about users. We use the cookie so users do not have to log in every time they use the service and the cookie will automatically expire if you do not visit the Mondaq website (or its affiliate sites) for 12 months. We also use the cookie to personalise a user's experience of the site (for example to show information specific to a user's region). As the Mondaq sites are fully personalised and cookies are essential to its core technology the site will function unpredictably with browsers that do not support cookies - or where cookies are disabled (in these circumstances we advise you to attempt to locate the information you require elsewhere on the web). However if you are concerned about the presence of a Mondaq cookie on your machine you can also choose to expire the cookie immediately (remove it) by selecting the 'Log Off' menu option as the last thing you do when you use the site.

Some of our business partners may use cookies on our site (for example, advertisers). However, we have no access to or control over these cookies and we are not aware of any at present that do so.

Log Files

We use IP addresses to analyse trends, administer the site, track movement, and gather broad demographic information for aggregate use. IP addresses are not linked to personally identifiable information.


This web site contains links to other sites. Please be aware that Mondaq (or its affiliate sites) are not responsible for the privacy practices of such other sites. We encourage our users to be aware when they leave our site and to read the privacy statements of these third party sites. This privacy statement applies solely to information collected by this Web site.

Surveys & Contests

From time-to-time our site requests information from users via surveys or contests. Participation in these surveys or contests is completely voluntary and the user therefore has a choice whether or not to disclose any information requested. Information requested may include contact information (such as name and delivery address), and demographic information (such as postcode, age level). Contact information will be used to notify the winners and award prizes. Survey information will be used for purposes of monitoring or improving the functionality of the site.


If a user elects to use our referral service for informing a friend about our site, we ask them for the friend’s name and email address. Mondaq stores this information and may contact the friend to invite them to register with Mondaq, but they will not be contacted more than once. The friend may contact Mondaq to request the removal of this information from our database.


This website takes every reasonable precaution to protect our users’ information. When users submit sensitive information via the website, your information is protected using firewalls and other security technology. If you have any questions about the security at our website, you can send an email to

Correcting/Updating Personal Information

If a user’s personally identifiable information changes (such as postcode), or if a user no longer desires our service, we will endeavour to provide a way to correct, update or remove that user’s personal data provided to us. This can usually be done at the “Your Profile” page or by sending an email to

Notification of Changes

If we decide to change our Terms & Conditions or Privacy Policy, we will post those changes on our site so our users are always aware of what information we collect, how we use it, and under what circumstances, if any, we disclose it. If at any point we decide to use personally identifiable information in a manner different from that stated at the time it was collected, we will notify users by way of an email. Users will have a choice as to whether or not we use their information in this different manner. We will use information in accordance with the privacy policy under which the information was collected.

How to contact Mondaq

You can contact us with comments or queries at

If for some reason you believe Mondaq Ltd. has not adhered to these principles, please notify us by e-mail at and we will use commercially reasonable efforts to determine and correct the problem promptly.